www.elsevier.com/locate/aos
Politicalconstraints,organizationdesignandperformance
measurementinChinaÕsstate-ownedenterprises
NealeG.O’Connor
aa,*,JohnnyDengb,YadongLuo
cDepartmentofAccountancy,CityUniversityofHongKong,83TatCheeAvenue,KowloonTong,Kowloon,HongKong
bRoutonElectricCoLtd.,MiaoshanDistrict,Wuhan,PRChina
cDepartmentofManagement,SchoolofBusinessAdministration,UniversityofMiami,FL33124,USA
Abstract
Thisstudydevelopsatheoreticalmodeltotesthowpoliticalconstraintsonlabordecisionsmediatetheeffectsofeconomicliberalizationforcesonaspectsoforganizationaldesignsuchasdelegation,performancemeasurement,andincentivesinChinesestate-ownedenterprises.Hypothesestestsusingalargesurveyofdivisionalmanagersgener-allyconfirmthemodel:thattheinfluenceofthreeliberalizationforces(industrylevelgrowthandforeignfirmcompe-tition,jointventureexperienceandstockmarketlisting)onorganizationdesignismediatedbypoliticalconstraints.Ó2005ElsevierLtd.Allrightsreserved.
Introduction
Since1997,moststate-ownedenterprises(SOEs)inChinahavebecomemarkedlymoreindependentasaresultofamassiveliberalizationprogram,whichhasnotonlycreatedgreaterautonomyforbusinessexpansionbuthasalsointroducedcompetitivepressureunderwhichSOEsstrivetogroworstruggletosurvivethroughsignificantimprovementsofproductivity,
efficiency,innovation,andservices.Toachievetheseends,thedevelopmentofamore‘‘Western’’micro-levelorganizationdesignisnowcommonlyviewedasthefundamentalforcethatdeterminesthesuccessfulrestructuringofSOEs(Jefferson,Rawski,&Zheng,1996;Qian,1996;Shirley&Xu,2001).1Forinstance,recentresearchindicatesthattheuseofincentiveschemesinChinaÕsSOEsenhancesproductivity(Qian,2001;Xu,2000;
ThetermÔWesternÕisusedtoreflecttheeconomicprescrip-tions(efficiencyrationale)thatunderliethechoiceoftheorganizationaldesigncomponents(forexample,delegation,performancemeasurement,andincentivecompensation)intheaccountingandeconomicsliterature(Milgrom&Roberts,1995).
1Correspondingauthor.Tel.:+85227888964;fax:+85227887944.
E-mailaddresses:acno@cityu.edu.hk(N.G.O’Connor),dengf@routon.com(J.Deng),yadong@miami.edu(Y.Luo).
*0361-3682/$-seefrontmatterÓ2005ElsevierLtd.Allrightsreserved.doi:10.1016/j.aos.2005.01.005
158N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
Zhuang&Xu,1996).Lee(2001)reportsincreaseddelegationduringtheprocessofthefinancialrestructuringofalargeSOE.Otherstudiesfindthatliberalizationforcessuchasmarketcompeti-tion(Firth,1996),foreignjointventureexperience(Firth,1996;OÕConnor,Chow,&Wu,2004),andstockmarketlisting(OÕConnoretal.,2004)areassociatedwiththelevelofadoptionofvariousWesternmanagementaccountingtechniques,includingperformancemeasurementsystems.
Todate,however,therehasbeenlittlesystem-aticexaminationofhowtheseorganizationalde-signcomponentsareconstrainedbypoliticalconditions,whichtendtobeanimportantfeatureofeconomiesintransition,especiallyChina(Qian,1996).Recentstudieshighlighttheprevalenceofpoliticalconstraints.Forinstance,Li(2000)pro-videsevidencethattightergovernmentalcontrolresultsinmoreunprofitableproductionandsur-plusemployment.Xu,Zhu,andLin(2002)findthatpoliticalinterferencetendstodominatelabordecisions,whereasotherdecisionsaredominatedbyagencycosts.AccordingtoQian(1996,p.429),‘‘understandingthisinteractionbetweentheeffectivecontrolbymanagersoversomedecisionsandtheultimatecontrolbythePartyandthegov-ernmentoverotherdecisionsisthekeytounder-standingtheproblemswiththepastreformandtheissuestobeaddressedinthefuture.’’Theques-tionofhowtobreakuptheoldvestedinterestsinstate-ownedindustryhasbeendescribedasa‘‘for-biddenarea’’ofreform,becauseitaffectsthegov-ernmentÕsabilitytoregulate,monitor,orcontrolemploymentandotherresourceallocationissues.‘‘ThecontradictionsinthesituationareobvioustomanyChineseenterprisemanagersandaca-demicanalysts,butthereisonlylimitedresearchonhowtoresolvethembecauseoftheissueÕsgreatpoliticalsensitivity.’’(Hassard,Sheehan,&Mor-ris,1999,p.76).
ThispaperextendstheliteratureonChineseSOEreformbyexaminingthemediatinginfluenceofpoliticalconstraintsonorganizationaldesigninChinaÕsSOEs.PoliticalconstraintsaredefinedinthispaperasthedegreetowhichgovernmentalauthoritiesandCommunistPartyrepresentativesintervene,regulate,orcontrolanSOEÕslabordeci-sions(hiring,firing,andpromotion).Asthese
politicalconstraintsareinplayalongwithmarketliberalizationforces(Li,2000),itislikelythattheeffectofliberalizationforcesontheorganizationaldesignordecisionsofSOEsismediatedbypoliti-calconstraints.Forexample,marketcompetitionhasapositivedirecteffectontheadoptionofWes-ternmanagementcontrols(e.g.,Firth,1996),butalsoanindirecteffectbecauseitisassociatedwithhighergrowthindustries,whichwerethefirsttoexperiencethereducedpoliticalconstraints(Chen,2000)thatcanslowtheadoptionofWesternman-agementcontrols.Thedirecteffectpotentiallypro-videsamisleadingimpressionoftheinfluenceofcompetition.Wesuggestthatthispossiblemediat-ingeffectisimportantbecause,inasocialistmar-keteconomysuchasChina,economicreformstakeplaceundervariouspoliticalconstraints,andaccordinglySOEsneedtocopewithnotonlyeconomictransformationandmarketliberaliza-tionbutalsopoliticalconstraintsandregulatoryconditions.
Wedevelopatheoreticalmodeltotestthemedi-atinginfluenceofpoliticalconstraintsontheasso-ciationsbetweenliberalizationforces,andtheuseofthreeorganizationaldesigncomponents(dele-gation,performancemeasurement,andincentives)withinSOEs.ConsistentwiththerecentChinare-formliterature,weuseagencytheorytodeveloptheseparatelinksinthemodel.2Weusethefirmastheunitofanalysisandfocusontheorganiza-tionaldesigncomponentsatthedivisionalman-agerlevelsuchasprofit-centermanagers(invariousdivisions,branches,orunits)andcost-cen-
2Researcherssuggestthatcollectiveculturalvalueschallengetheself-interestassumptionthatunderliesagencytheoryandthedesignofmanyaccountingcontrolsystems(e.g.,Howell&Sakurai,1992).However,thereisgrowingevidenceoftheprevalenceofself-interestedbehaviorinChina.Forexample,Chen(1995)findsthatmainlandChineseemployeesinreform-orientedcompaniesactuallyfavormoremerit-basedpay.InanotherstudyinvolvingUS,Japanese,andChinesesubjects,Bailey,Chen,andDou(1997)findthattheChinese‘‘consis-tentlydepartedfromprediction,’’hypothesizingtheeffectofcollectivismontheirpreferenceforperformancefeedback.TheirresultsledthemtoconcludethattheChinesemay‘‘departfromcollectivistvaluesinwaysthatresembleAmericansmorethanJapanese’’(pp.605,620).
N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177159
termanagers(invariousdepartments),asthedeci-sionsandactionsofmanagersatthislevelarelikelytohaveafargreatereffectontheenterprisethanthoseoflowerlevelmanagers(OÕConnoretal.,2004).WeuseananalyticalframeworkthatwasdevelopedbyJensenandMeckling(1992),MilgromandRoberts(1992,1995),andBrickley,Smith,andZimmerman(1995,2001),inwhichthedelegationofdecision-makingauthority(dele-gation),objectiveperformancemeasures,andincentivecompensationwithinanorganizationÕshierarchyjointlyconstitutetheorganizationÕsde-sign.Theconsiderationoftheinterdependenciesamongthesecomponentsaddsanotherdimensiontoourunderstandingoforganizationaldesignandisconsistentwithrecentstudiesinthemanagement(Mendelson,2000),economics(Delmastro,2002)andaccounting(Nagar,2002)literatures.Forexample,Nagar(2002)findsthatunderstandingtheinfluenceoffirmgrowthonthestrengthofincentivesisenhancedwhentheinterdependencyofdelegationandincentivesistakenintoconsideration.
Theremainderofthepaperisorganizedasfol-lows.Thenextsectiondevelopsthethreehypothe-sesthatcomprisethemodel.Theresearchmethodsandmeasurementofthevariablesarethenex-plained,followedbytheresults.Thepapercon-cludeswithadiscussionofthefindings.
TheoryandhypothesesTheoreticalmodel
Liberalizationandpoliticalconstraints
OneofthemainthrustsofrecentSOEreformshasbeentoencourageSOEsingrowthindustriesincertainlocationstoseekalternativesourcesofcapitaltodecreasetheirrelianceonthestate.ThemajorliberalizationforcesthatpertaintoChi-neseSOEsincludemarketcompetition(industrygrowth,foreigncompetition),exportmarketsales,jointventureexperience,andstockexchangelist-ing(Huang&Duncan,1997;Lin,2000;Lin,Cai,&Li,1998;Xu,2000).Inthetransitionfromcen-tralplanningtoamarketeconomy,however,SOEoperationsarecomplicatedbecauseliberalization
forcesandstateinfluencescoexistandjointlycon-strainSOEmanagementandorganizationalchange(Child,1994).Inparticular,opaque,uncer-tain,andunpredictableregulatoryframeworksthatareformedbybothcentralandlocalgovern-mentsheightenthecomplexityoforganizingpro-ductionandmarketing,andoftennullifythestrategicplanningofSOEs(Linetal.,1998).
OneoftheprimechannelsinwhichtheStatecontrolsSOEsisinthearealabordecisionmaking.PoliticalconstraintsonlabordecisionmakinginSOEstakeplacethroughvariouspolicyregula-tionsandgovernmentrepresentatives(i.e.,partysecretaries,boardmembers,orstate-asset-manage-mentrepresentatives).SuchcontrolisorchestratedviathepowerofCommunistPartyrepresentativestointerveneinenterprisedecisionmaking,includ-ingtheappointing,firing,andpromotionofdivi-sionalmanagers(Hassardetal.,1999).AlthoughpreviousSOEreformsadoptedvariousrestructur-ingpolicies,thefundamentalprincipleoftheso-called‘‘Partycontrolspersonnel’’policyremainedunchallenged.
Whenpersonnelmanagementsystems,includ-ingauthorityregimesandperformanceevaluationstructures,areinfusedwithpoliticalconsiderationsthroughgovernmentinterference(e.g.,imposing‘‘caps’’toreduceincomedisparity,orrestrictingthedismissalofredundantorunproductiveemployees),thebenefitstobegainedbyadoptingthesecomponentsbecomerestricted,andagencyhazardswithintheSOEhierarchybecomemoreserious.SuchrestrictionsorhazardsarewhatShle-iferandVishney(1994)callthepoliticalcoststhatareassociatedwithprivatizationandliberaliza-tion.Thepoliticalcostsmodelstatesthattheeffec-tiverestructuringormodernizationofpublicenterprisesislargelydependentontheextenttowhichemploymentcontrolrightsaretransferredtomanagement(fromgovernment)intheprocessofcorporatization(Shleifer&Vishney,1994,p.1015).Thisisexpectedtodirectlyaffectthefunc-tionalityoftheorganizationaldesignandtheeffec-tivenessofitscomponents(Pannier,1996).Organizationaldesigncomponents
Topmanagementplaysamajorroleinformu-latingorganizationaldesign,includingdecisions
160N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
abouthowmuchdecisionauthoritytodelegatetodivisionalmanagers,andhowtostructuretheper-formanceevaluationandrewardsystemsothatqualifiedemployeesareattracted,retained,andmotivated(Brickleyetal.,2001).3Whendelegatedtomanagersinvariousprofitorcostcenters,deci-sionrights—whicharetherightstodecideonandtakeaction—canboostorganizationaladaptationandmarketresponsiveness(Bushman,Indjejikian,&Penno,2000).KnowledgetransfercostswithinanorganizationÕshierarchyarelowerwhendeci-sion-makingrightsaremovedtoindividualswhooperateatorganizationaledges(Christie,Joye,&Watts,2003).4Firmsalsoneedtomeasurethebehaviorandefficiencyofdivisionalmanagerswithamixofobjectiveandsubjectiveperformancemeasures,andtorewardthemonthisbasis(Haveman,1992;Jensen&Meckling,1995).Thegreateruseofobjectiveperformancemeasures,whichisde-finedinthisstudyastherelativeweightingplacedonobjectivemeasuresintheobjective/subjectiveperformancemeasurementmix,meansthatthemeasurementisincreasingly‘‘freefrompersonalbias’’(Merchant,1989,p.26),whichinturnre-ducesthepotentialgainsfrominfluencingactivi-tiesasperceivedbytheagent(Prendergast,1999).5Objectiveperformancemeasuresalsopro-videanimportantnormofexpectedperformance,ashighuncertaintyinperformanceevaluationmayotherwiseinhibitthedevelopmentofentrepreneur-
3Thisisnotanexhaustiveviewofcontrols.Controlsalsocommunicatestrategyanddevelopcapabilitiesintheorgani-zation(Simons,1995).4Jensen(1998)definesknowledgetransfercostsalongaspecific(general)knowledgecontinuumthatmeasureshigh(low)transfercosts.Werefertoknowledgetransfercostsintermsofthiscontinuum.SeeChristieetal.(2003)foranextensivereviewofdelegationandknowledgetransfercosts.5Theaccountingliteratureidentifiesseveraleconomicattri-butesofperformancemeasures(informativeness,sensitivity,noise,andobjectivity:Moers,2005).TheobjectivityattributeofperformancemeasurementisparticularlycriticalintheChinesetransitionaleconomy(andthereforethisstudy)becauseper-formancemeasurementsystemsatthedivisionalandlowermanagementlevelshavetraditionallybeenhighlysubjective(dependentonsuperiorpersonalassessment)(Byrd&Tidrick,1991).
ialattitudesandbehavioramongmanagers,thusenlargingagencycosts(Baker,Gibbons,&Mur-phy,1994).Subjectivityalsoplaysanimportantroleinefficientperformancemonitoringbecauseitcanreducegamingactivities(Gibbs,Merchant,VanderStede,&Vargus,2004;Ittner,Larcker,&Meyer,2003).However,intheChinareformcontextsubjectivityinperformanceevaluationhastraditionallybeenusedtopreservethestatusquointermsofcentralizedpowerintheSOEratherthanasanefficiencyenhancingmechanism(Byrd&Tidrick,1991).
Finally,agencytheoryprescribestheuseofincentivecompensationthatisbasedontheper-formanceofagents,becausetheresultantinforma-tionasymmetriesmaketheirbehaviorcostlyordifficulttoobserve(Eisenhardt,1989;Gerhart&Milkovich,1990).Theuseofincentivesisdefinedinthisstudyasthesizeofmonetaryrewardsthatdistinguishbetweenlevelsofmanagerperfor-mance.Thesethreecomponentsareinterrelatedandinseparableinsuchamannerthatperfor-mancemonitoringisafoundationonwhichre-wardandauthorityallocationsarebuiltandappraised,whiledecisionrightsandincentivesaccentuateeachotherinacompetitiveyetvolatileenvironment(Nagar,2002;Tosi,Katz,&Gomez-Mejia,1997).ConsistentwiththeorganizationaldesignframeworkdevelopedbyJensenandMec-kling(1992)andothers(Brickleyetal.,2001,Chapter11;Milgrom&Roberts,1992,Chapters4&12)wedevelophypothesesforthejointchoiceofcomponentsthatcomprisetheorganizationaldesign.6Eachofthelinksinthemodelisdevel-opedinturn(seeFig.1).
6Thereissomedebateoverwhetherthesecomponentsareactuallychosensimultaneouslyinorganizations,withregardtoeachother,orarechoseninsomekindofsimplifyingunidirectionalorder(cf.Luft&Shields,2003;Nagar,2002).Thatquestionisnotexaminedinthisstudy.Inaddition,bytakinganorganizationallevelofanalysis,wefocusonvariationsintheuseoforganizationaldesigncomponentsacrossSOEsthatfacedifferentlevelsofexogenousinfluences.Oursurveydesignrestrictedusfromeffectivelyexaminingtheinfluencesofseveralpotentialendogenousvariablessuchasstrategy,taskuncertainty,andhumanassetspecificity(Fisher&Govindarajan,1992).
N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177161
Liberalization PoliticalSOE forces H2constraints H3Organizational Industry growthon laborDesign& Foreign decision - Delegation competition making- Objective Export sales performance Joint venture H1measuresexperience - IncentivesStock exchangelisting Fig.1.Theoreticalmodel.UseoforganizationaldesigncomponentsinChineseenterprises
Liberalizationforcesandorganizationaldesigncomponents
Previousstudieshavedevelopedgeneralexpec-tationsfortheSOEadoptionofmanagementaccounting/controlsandhaveexaminedtheinflu-enceofliberalizationforcesononlysomeoftheorganizationaldesigncomponentsinthisstudy(e.g.,Firth,1996;OÕConnoretal.,2004).7Toexaminethemediatingeffectofpoliticalcon-straints,wefirstneedtoproposethemaineffectofliberalizationforcesontheorganizationalde-signcomponents.Wedevelophypothesesforindustrylevel,marketopenness,andmarketfunc-tion-relatedliberalizationforces.
Whenanindustryisfreedfromgovernmentcontrolasaresultofliberalization,rapidmarketgrowthusuallyensues.However,thisgrowthmaynotlastverylongbecauseliberalizationalsoencourageslocalandforeigncompetition(Perkins,1994).Followingagencylogic,SOEsinfastergrowingindustriesthathavehigherlevelsoffor-eigncompetition,arelikelytodependmoreontheknowledgeandexperienceofdivisionalman-agersandthusfacehigherknowledgetransfercosts(Jensen,1998).Thedelegationofdecisionauthoritytodivisionalsalesmanagersenablesthemtoeffectivelyusetheirinformationadvantage
7Forexample,OÕConnoretal.Õs(2004)constructcomprisesfivedimensions,onlytwoofwhich(approvalproceduresandperformancetargets)matchthedimensionsinthisstudy(delegationandobjectiveperformancemeasures).Theyfindthatthesedimensionsaresignificantlyassociatedwithonlyonetypeofliberalizationforce(jointventureexperience).
toquicklyrespondtotheenvironment(Bakeretal.,1994).Thereisalsogreaterpressureonseniormanagementtomakeaccuratejudgmentsaboutmanagerperformancewithrespecttoquality,deliveryandbudgettargets.Li(1997,p.1101)notesthatmarketcompetitionhas‘‘gener-atedconsiderablepressuretoimprovebothcostandquality’’,whichinturnincreasestheneedformoreextensivecontrolssuchasperformancemeasurementsystems.
Pressuretoadoptmoreobjectiveperformancemeasurementandperformance-basedincentivesystemstoretainandattractqualitymanagersismorelikelyinfastergrowingindustriesthathavehigherconcentrationsofforeigninvestedenter-prises(i.e.jointventureorwholly-ownedsubsidi-aries).Insuchindustries,SOEscouldsufferfromthelossofmanagerstohigherpayingcompetitors;asaresult,‘‘someexpertshaveproposedraisingmanagerÕssalariesbasedonannualperformancereviews.’’(Zhongguo,1997,p.1).ForeigninvestedenterprisestypicallyattractthebestChinesegraduatesandhavedevelopedtheleadingexam-plesofmodernmanagersinChina(Branine,1996,p.37).
H1.1:Therewillbeapositiverelationshipbetweenthestrengthofindustry-levelindustrialgrowthandforeigncompetitionandtheuseofdelegation(H1.1a),therelativeuseofobjectiveperformancemeasures(H1.1b),andthelevelofincentives(H1.1c).
Atthefirmlevelmarketopenness-relatedliber-alizationforces(jointventurepartneringandre-latedexportopportunities)provideSOEswithfinancialincentives(accesstoforeigncapital)andoperationalprivileges(e.g.,priorityinaccessinginnovativetechnologyfromtheforeignpartner,includingWesternmanagementtechniques)thatarelikelytospurtheadoptionofamoreWesternorganizationaldesign.Asjointventuresalsopro-videaccesstoexportmarkets,SOEsareabletogainaccesstofurthercapitalintermsofrefundsofvalueaddedtaxandtheretentionofforeignex-changeearnings.TheseinstitutionalincentivespropelSOEstoallocateimportantresourcestocontrolthedeliveryandqualityofproducts,whichinturnincreasesthescopefortheuseof
162N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
delegation,performancemeasures,andincentivestoplanandcontrolsuchpractices.Forexample,greaterdelegationcanhelpinmoretimelyre-sponsestothequalityandon-timedeliveryde-mandsofexportcustomers.Similarly,motivatingdivisionalmanagers,especiallythoseinproductdivisions,toexportmoreisaprerequisitemeasure,whichmaymakeitnecessaryforSOEexecutivestolinkincentiveswithdivisionalmanagersÕexportperformance,toensurethatthecorporatepriorityinexportisadequatelymaterialized.
Inadditiontoprovidingaccesstoexportmar-kets,jointventuresprovideoperationalprivilegesthroughthesecondmentofstaffandexpatriatetraining,whichenablesSOEstolearnperceivedbestpracticestotakeadvantageofsuchexportopportunities(Branine,1996;Firth,1996).JointventuresprovideaccesstoWesternmanagementcontrolsystemsthatwouldnormallybeexpensivetointroduce.Inaddition,theyprovidethetrainingandsupportthatensuresthesuccessfulimplemen-tationofsuchsystems.This,inturn,increasesthelikelihoodthatjointventurepartneringSOEshaveagreatercapabilitytodelegatedecisions,andthattheyhaveagreaterrangeofperformancemeasuresattheirdisposaltouseinevaluatingandrewardingemployees.
GoodallandWarner(1999,pp.25–26)notethatforeign-ChineseJVshavethepotentialtopro-videtheseedsofglobalbargaininginthreepoten-tiallykeyareasofhumanresourcemanagement:employmentcontracts,rewardsystems,andwel-fare/socialinsurance.Firth(1996)andOÕConnoretal.(2004)findthatSOEswithgreaterforeignjointventureexperiencetendtohavehigherlevelsofuseofWesternmanagementcontrols(e.g.bud-getingandperformancetargets)thandotheirnon-jointventurecounterparts.Firth(1996)alsofindsthatSOEswithgreaterexportsalestendtohavehigherlevelsofuseofWesternmanagementcon-trolsthantheirnon-exportcounterparts.Thesecontrolsincludetheuseofbudgetsetting,which,inthetransitionaleconomysetting,islikelytoin-creasethedegreeofobjectivityintheperformancemeasurement.
H1.2:Therewillbeapositiverelationshipbetweenexportmarketsalesandjointventureexperience
andtheuseoforganizationaldesigncomponentsintermsofdelegation(H1.2a),therelativeuseofobjectiveperformancemeasures(H1.2b),andthelevelofincentives(H1.2c).
Animportantmarketfunction-relatedliberal-izationforceisallowingSOEstolistonstockex-changes(Li,2000).Thesharesofover1000firmsarelistedandexchangedinChinaÕsstockmarket,withamarketcapitalizationofover2000billionYuan(ChinaSecuritiesRegulatoryCommission,2001).Inaddition,thecentralgovernmentnowal-lowsprivatecompaniestoacquireagreaternum-berofpoorlymanagedlistedSOEs,whichhasloweredtheaveragegovernmentshareholdingto30%(Cheng,2001).StockmarketlistingspressureSOEstoadoptmoreadvancedmanagementsys-tems,suchasperformancemeasurementsystems,toenhanceorganizationaltransparency,efficiency,andproductivity(Cheng,2001;Megginson&Net-ter,2001;Pannier,1996).OÕConnoretal.(2004)foundapositiverelationbetweentheuseofman-agementaccounting/controlsandstockexchangelisting.BecausemostSOEsthatarelistedonChinaÕsexchangeshavedecentralizedorganiza-tionalstructures,divisionalmanagersinvariousprofitorcostcentersarerealcontributorswhoareresponsiblefortheentirecompanyÕsaccountingperformance(e.g.,returnoninvest-ment,earningspershare,andreturnonassets)andmarketingperformance(e.g.,salesgrowth,marketshare,andassetturnover).Thesecondi-tionsincreasetheopportunitytousemoreobjec-tivemeasuresandtiemanagerrewardstoperformanceoutcomes(Keating,1997;Lambert&Larcker,1987).Inlightoftheabovediscussion,wehypothesize:
H1.3:Therewillbeapositiverelationshipbetweenstockmarketlistingandtheuseoforganiza-tionaldesigncomponentsintermsofdelegation(H1.3a),therelativeuseofobjectiveperformancemeasures(H1.3b),andthelevelofincentives(H1.3c).
Liberalizationforcesandpoliticalconstraints
Thelevelofpoliticalconstraintsvariesaccord-ingtoseveralfactors,suchassize,industrycompe-
N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177163
titionandgrowth,export,foreignpartneringopportunitiesandstockexchangelisting.Apartfromfirmsize,thevigorofpoliticalconstraintsoverdifferentSOEsisalsolikelytovaryaccordingtocompetition,growth,andtheextentofexportandforeignpartneringopportunities(Linetal.,1998).8Firmsindifferentindustriesandregionsaresubjecttoidiosyncratictreatmentbygovern-mentalpoliciesonhumanresourcemanagement.Forinstance,Chen(2000)arguesthatinsomeindustrieswithlessgrowth,export,andemploy-mentopportunities,thegovernmenthasagreaterinfluenceoverhumanresources,therebyconstrain-ingtheadoptionofmoreefficientformsofenter-prise.SOEsincoastalcitieshavegreaterexportandforeignpartneringopportunities,therebyreducingSOEfinancialrelianceonthestate.Finally,bywayofdilutionofownership,thegovernmenthaslessinfluenceonpubliclylistedSOEs.Forexample,inastudyofChinaÕspubliclylistedfirms,Wang(2003)reportsasignificantpositiverelationshipbetweenthelevelofstateownershipandthedegreeofgovernmentinter-vention.
Theseinfluences,however,arenotindependentofeachother.Forexample,duringthe1990sper-iodoftransition,thefastergrowingindustrieswerefirstopeneduptoforeigndirectinvestment,andwerethussubjecttohighermarketcompeti-tionthantheirlowergrowthcounterparts(Chen,2000).Hence,bothindustrygrowth(directly)andmarketcompetition(indirectly)influencethelevelofpoliticalconstraints.Basedonthesefac-tors,wehypothesize:
H2:Therewillbeanegativerelationshipbetweenthestrengthofliberalizationforces(industrialgrowth,foreigncompetition,exportmarketsales,jointventureexperience,andstockmarketlisting)andthelevelofpoliticalconstraints.
8Weincludedsize(numberofemployeesintheSOE)asacontrolvariableintheanalysisbecauseitispositivelyassoci-atedwithbothagencyandpoliticalcostsandhasbeenanimportantcriterionintheSOEreforms(Goodall&Warner,1999;OÕConnoretal.,2004).
Politicalconstraintsandorganizationaldesigncomponents
Directinterferenceinthegreateruseoforgani-zationaldesigncomponentsbyresidentPartysec-retariesisgenerallyprofoundbecausetheoverridingjobofthesesecretariesisthemanage-mentofSOEpersonnel.First,whenPartyrepre-sentativeshavegreatercontroloverpersonnel,theselectionofdivisionalmanagersmaybemadeonpoliticalgroundsandnotprofitgrounds.Thiseffectivelyreducesthebenefitsof(andhencetheuseof)delegationtomanagerswhoaresupposedtakegreaterresponsibilityforfront-linedecisionsinthecontextofincreasingliberalization.Theresultingcentralizationofdecisions,althoughcon-sideredtobeasefficientinsomecontexts,ismorelikelytocomeatthecostoforganizationaleffi-ciency.AccordingtoQian(2001),withthePartysecretaryactingasa‘‘superowner’’forthemain-tenanceofsocialstability,corporategovernancethatpromotesorganizationalefficiencyishardtoestablish.
Second,politicalconstraintsdecreasetheinten-tionofSOEexecutivestosharpenmanagerialdis-cretionandimproveorganizationalefficiencythroughtheuseofobjectiveperformancemeasuresandincentivesystems(Branine,1996;Peng&Heath,1996).9Partybureaucratsgenerallylacktheabilityandtheincentivestomakedecisionsaboutmanagerialselectionandcompensationaccordingtobusinesscriteriabecausetheyaremainlypoliticallymotivated(Huang&Duncan,1997;Jefferson&Rawski,1994).Therefore,penal-tiesforpoorlyperformingmanagersmaybere-strictedonthebasisofmaintainingastableworkplaceundertheguiseofgradualreform.This,inturn,reducesthevisibilityandcredibilityofobjectiveperformancemeasuresandincentives,thuscurtailingtheiradoptionorlimitingtheireffectiveness(Shirley&Xu,1998).
9Politicalconstraintsalsohavethepotentialtodecreaseagencycoststhroughthemonitoringthatisprovidedbythegovernmentrepresentative.Weargue,however,thatthissubstitutioneffect(governmentmonitoringoforganizationaldesigncomponents)isalessefficientoptionduetothedualroles(politicalandeconomic)ofthegovernment.Thatquestionwasnotdirectlytestedinthisstudy.
164N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
Theseexpectationsarepartlysupportedbyexistingevidence.Forexample,whileLi(1997)findsthattheincreaseduseofincentivesisrelatedtoincreasesinmarginalandtotalfactorproductiv-ity,ShirleyandXu(1998)donot,andattributethefailureofcontractstopoliticalconstraints(e.g.theinabilityofthegovernmenttofollowthroughonpromisedactionsandtheinefficientmonitoringofcontracts).Xuetal.(2002)findthatpoliticalconstraintstendtodominatelabordecisions,whileotherdecisionsaredominatedbyagencycosts.Thus,althoughpoliticalconstraintsappeartohaveadirectinfluenceondelegation,followingagencylogiconecanexpectthatthesupportingcontrolcomponents(objectiveperformancemea-suresandincentives)willbeaffected,albeitindi-rectly.Westatethehypothesesintermsofthegeneralexpectationabouttheassociationbetweenpoliticalconstraintsandorganizationaldesigncomponents.
H3:Therewillbeanegativerelationshipbetweenthelevelofpoliticalconstraintsandtheuseofdel-egation(H3a),therelativeuseofobjectiveperfor-mancemeasures(H3b),andthelevelofincentives(H3c).
ResearchmethodsSampleanddatacollection
Wecollectedsurveydatafrom502divisionallevelmanagersin502SOEs.Therespondentsrep-resentedarangeoffunctionssuchasaccountancy(identifiedn=68),administration(92),humanre-sourcesmanagement(30),production(88),salesandmarketing(92),andresearchanddevelopment(36).AccesstothemanagerswasobtainedthroughalistofexecutiveMBAalumniwhoworkedinSOEsthatoperatedintwoChineseprovinces(HubeiandGuangdong).Thesurveywasdistrib-utedin1999tofourseparateMBAgroupsacrosstwoMainlandChineseuniversities,andcompletedinclass.WhileitwaspossiblethatmorethanonemanagercouldcomefromoneSOE,thiscaseishighlyunlikelyforthefollowingreasons.First,therespondentsindicatedover20specific
industries,andthatnotwoSOEsfromthesameindustrywereindicatedtohavethesamesizeorthesameage.Second,basedondiscussionswiththeMBAprogrammeleaders,theselectionprocessiscompetitiveandindividualandtheman-agersarenotsponsoredbytheSOEs.Moreover,thereareover10,000SOEsinthevicinityofthetwouniversitieswheretheMBAprogrammesaretaught.
WeconsideredissuesthatwereassociatedwiththereliabilityandvalidityofresponsesfromMBAstudentswhendesigningthestudy.First,MBAstudentsmightonlyrepresentlesstradi-tionalSOEs,suchasthosefurtherdownthepriv-atizationpath,andnotaverageSOEs.Second,MBAstudentsmightthinkdifferently,andarethuslikelytobeaconcernforstudiesthatseektoexamineindividuallevelphenomenasuchascognitivecharacteristics.Forexample,PriemandRosenstein(2000,p.517)contrasttheÔcausemapsÕofMBAstudentswiththoseofCEOswithoutsucheducationandfindthatMBArespondentsexhibitmuchstrongercontingentthinking.Webalancedtheseissuesagainstthedifficultyofobtainingpri-marydataonChineseSOEsandthebenefitsofexploringarelevantresearchquestion,giventhelimitedlarge-scalesurveysonSOEmanagementpracticesintheChinareformliterature.
Wealsoconsideredthelevelofanalysisthatwasrequiredinourstudy,andtookstepstotestthevalidityoftheresponses.First,wefocusedtheanalysisattheorganizationlevelratherthantheindividuallevel.Forexample,weaskedtherespon-dentstoassessthelevelofparticularcontrolsinplaceintheirfirm,ratherthanaskingfortheirpref-erencesortheirlevelofpersonaljobsatisfaction.Second,wetooktwostepstotestthevalidityofresponsesbycomparisonwithindustrycharacteris-tics(seetheresultssection).Therespondentswerepaidanincentive(100Yuan)tocompletethesurvey.Thiswasnecessarygiventhesurveylength(6pages)andthegreatersenseofmanagertimeurgency.
Measuringinstrument
AsummaryofthesurveymeasuresispresentedinTable1.Thesurveyinstrumentcomprisedsev-
N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
Table1
Confirmatoryfactoranalysis—variablesusedinthemodel(n=502)Factor1.Size
Abouthowmanyfulltimeemployeesdoesyourfirmhave?
2.Liberalizationforces—industrylevelGWHIndustry—averagesalesgrowth(1996–1998)FCMPIndustry—percentageofforeignfirms
3.Liberalizationforces—firmlevelEXPORTWhatpercentageofyourfirmÕsoutputisexportedoutofthecountry?JVDoesyourfirmhaveajointventurewithaforeignenterprise?Yes(1)No(0)STOKIsyourfirmlistedonstockexchange?Yes(1)No(0)
0.7740.929
0.9150.4860.5280.688
165
Factorscore
4.Politicalconstraints
Towhatextentdoeseachofthefollowingparties(people)affectthehumanresourcesdecisions
(hiring,firing,andpromotion)ofcostorprofitcentermanagersinyourfirm?Theresponsescalerangedfrom1(notatall)to7(averyhighextent)PC1Governmentagency/ministryresponsibleforyourindustry0.648PC2CommunistPartyrepresentative0.847
WhatistheextenttowhichauthorityisgiventotheCommunistPartyrepresentativefromthegovernmentministrytomakethefollowingdecisionsforyourfirm?Theresponsescalerangedfrom1(notatall)to7(averyhighextent)PC3Thepromotionofcostorprofitcentermanagers0.931PC4Thehiringofcostorprofitcentermanagers0.939PC5Thefiringofcostorprofitcentermanagers0.9155.Delegation
Towhatextentisauthoritydelegatedtothecost/profitcentermanagersfromthegeneralmanager(orseniormangers)tomakethefollowingdecisionsforthefirm?A5itemresponsescalerangedfrom0(notatall)to5(averylargeextent)DEC1Developmentofnewproductsandprojects0.463DEC2Thehiringandfiringofpersonnel0.607DEC3Sourcingofinputs(materialsandparts,etc.)0.692DEC4Settingthebudgetforeachfunctionordivision0.783DEC5Spendingitemsinthebudgetforeachfunctionordivision0.802DEC6Spendingitemsoutsidethebudgetforeachfunctionordivision0.6356.Objectiveperformancemeasures
Whatistherelativeweightgivento(alistoffour)objectivecriteriaor(alistoffour)subjectivecriteriainevaluatingtheperformanceofcostorprofitcentermanagers?A5itemresponsescalerangedfrom‘‘100%Obj’’(Objectivemeasuresarethemostimportant)to‘‘100%Subj’’(Subjectivemeasuresarethemostimportant)in25%increments.Thecodingforanalysisrangedfrom0%to100%objectivemeasuresOBJ1Increasingtheirresponsibilities0.674OBJ2Increasingtheirvariablebonussalary—basedonindividualperformance0.804OBJ3Increasingtheirvariablebonussalary—basedoncost/profitcenterperformance0.783
0.713OBJ4Increasingtheirvariablebonussalary—basedonoverallfirmperformance
OBJ5Determiningthenewcontractterms(ornon-renewal)attheendofthecurrentcontract0.6767.Incentives
Merit-basedmonetaryincentives
A5itemresponsescalerangedfrom0(notatall)to5(veryhighextent)REW1Rewardsaretiedtoanaccountingearningmeasures(e.g.salesrevenue,
returnonequity,operatingearnings,netincomebeforetax)
REW2Rewardsaretiedtoquantitativemeasures(e.g.productionoutput,
productioncosts,productionqualitytargets,salesgrowthtargets)
0.831
0.838
(continuedonnextpage)
166
Table1(continued)FactorREW3REW4
N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
Factorscore
TheextenttowhichcompensationcontractsclearlyspecifyhowcompensationisrelatedtomanagerperformancerelativetotheirdepartmentÕsbudgetWhatisthelevelofearningsofthe(a)highest10%and,(b)lowest10%performingmanagers?
A6itemresponsescaleforeachquestionrangedfrom:
$Yuan<=1000,1001–2500,2501–4000,4001–6000,6001–10000,>10000.Thegapbetweentheselevelsofearningswasdividedbythelowestperformingmanagerstoobtaina%score
0.7250.833
eralcategoricalanddescriptivequestionsinaddi-tiontoninepartswithnon-categoricalresponsesthatwereanchoredon5and7pointLikertscales.Severalissuesrelatingtothesurveydesignwereconsidered.First,themeasurementofthecon-structsinthesurveywasbaseduponthoseofsev-eralarticlesinthemanagement(Killing,1983)andmanagementaccountingliterature(Baiman,Larc-ker,&Rajan,1995;Baker,Jensen,&Murphy,1988,1994;Shields&Young,1993).BasedonaprevioussurveyofChineseSOEs(Firth,1996)andactualsitevisits,weexpandedthecontentofthesurveytoincludepoliticalconstraintsandlib-eralizationforces.10Second,itwasimportanttodesigntheques-tionstoreflecttheChinacontext.Initially,meet-ingswereconductedwithamainlandChineseprofessorandaVicePresidentofFinancefromalargeprivatecompanyinShenzhen(1998),afterwhichnumerousphonecallsande-mailswereex-changed.Thiscommunicationenabledustoagreeonseveralconstructsthatwereconsideredrelevanttothepaceofhumanresourcemanagementre-forminChineseSOEs,suchasitemsthatcom-prisedpoliticalconstraints.Wewerealsoabletoagreeontheinfluenceofseveralliberalizationforcesthathadalreadybeendiscussedintheliter-ature(seeFirth,1996).Anotherissuewasensuringthatthesalaryrangewhichweusedtoobtainre-sponsesaboutthelevelofbaseandbonuspayequatedwiththerangeofSOEsalariesinthetwolocations.
Aspartofanearlierproject,oneoftheauthorsconductedcasestudiesoftheuseofmanagementcontrolmechanismsinfourSOEsinShanghai.Thecasestudiesinvolvedhalf-dayvisitstoeachSOEinDecember1997.
10PriorexperienceincollectingdatainChinaalsoaidedthedesignofthescales.Forexample,basedonpastsurveyresearchinChina,theresearchersfoundthatitwasimportanttoexpresslylabeleachanchoroftheitemsthatrequiredaresponseonaLikertscale.ManyversionsofthesurveywereproducedbasedonthreemeetingsbetweentheinvestigatorsinApril,May,andJune1999.ThisrefinementprocessincludedseveraltranslationsfromEnglishintoChineseandthesubsequentbacktranslationofseveralvariablesanditems.11Toensureinternalreliability,abilingualChineseresearchprofessortranslatedthefinalversionofthesurveyintoMandarin.Back-translation,changes,andcorrectionsweremadetothistrans-lationbyanotherChineseprofessor.
Finally,weconsideredcommonresponsebiasissues.Aswithanyattempttocollectandanalyzedatausingasurveyinstrumentthequestionofassessmentandself-reportingarose(Young,2000).Weaddressedthisissueinseveralways.Forexample,weuseddifferentresponsescalesforthedifferentsetsofitemsthatpertainedtoeachconstruct.Wealsoreversedtheitemsthatpertainedtoobjectiveperformancemea-sures.Wealsousedarchivaldatatomeasureindustryliberalizationforces(asexplainedinthenextpart).
Liberalizationforcesandpoliticalconstraints
Followingtherecentreformliteratureweiden-tifiedfourmainvariablesascomprisingliberaliza-tionforces.Attheindustrylevelthelatentfactor
TheEnglishandChineseversionsofthequestionnaireareavailablefromtheauthorsuponrequest.
11N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
Table2
DescriptivestatisticsofvariablesurveyitemsaAlpha
ExogenousfactorsLiberalizationforces
Industry—averagesalesgrowth(1996–1998)bIndustry—percentageofforeignfirmsExportsales—percentageofsalesexportJointventureexperienceStockexchangelistingcPoliticalconstraints
OrganizationaldesignDelegation
ObjectiveperformancemeasuresIncentives
Incentives—%Gapb/wtopandbottom10%Controlvariable
Size—fulltimeemployees
ab167
MeanSDMaxMin
0.9210.7400.7990.7820.100d15.43%14.14%17.82%15.94%22.51%12.3317.68268.94%8.7652.91%3020
11.79%9.77%38.32%36.64%41.81%7.504.8584.99%2.7868.20%9395
55%33%100%100%100%25.0030.00500%15.00350.00%80000
À20%2%0%0%0%0.000.000.00%0.000.00%400
Allwithin-organizationmeasuresrelatetothedivisionalcost/profitcentermanagerlevel;n=502.
Over20industrieswererepresentedinthesample.Thelargestrepresentationswere:ElectronicsandCommunicationEquipment(88),Non-metalMineralProducts(77),TransportationEquipmentManufacturing(55),Construction(38),ChemicalRawMaterialandChemicalProducts(31),SpecialEquipmentManufacturing(14),Textiles(9),Electricity,Steam,HotWaterProductionandSupplies(8),Trading(7),MedicineManufacturing(6),ManufacturingofFoods(4),ElectricalMachineryandEquipment(2),TobaccoProcessing,Instruments,Meters,EducationalandOfficeEquipment,EducationalandSportsProductsManufacturing.Averagesalesgrowthforthethreeyears(1996–1998),andthenumberofforeignfirmsineachindustrywastakenfromtheChinaMarketsYearbook(2000).72.87%ofthesamplewaslocatedinGuangdong(consideredasaspecialeconomiczone),while27.13%waslocatedinHubei(consideredasaninlandprovince).cIndicatesthatadichotomousresponse(forexample,yes(1)orno(0))wasobtainedforthisvariable.dPearsoncorrelationbetweensalarygapbetweentopandbottom10%performingmanagersandincentivesscale(REW1ÀREW3)(p=0.026).
ofindustryliberalizationforceswasmeasuredwithtwoobservablemeasures:industrysalesgrowthandforeignfirmconcentration.IndustrysalesgrowthandtheextentofforeignfirmconcentrationweretakenfromtheChinaMarketsYearbook(2000),whichconsistsof550industrialcodes(atthe2digitlevel).Twentydifferentindustrycodeswererepresentedinourdata(seethefootnoteinTable2).Foreachindustry,themarketgrowthforthethreeyearsto1998wasaveraged.Forfor-eignfirmconcentration,thepercentageofforeignfirmsineachindustrywascomputed.Weusedthismeasuretoproxyfortheextentofforeigncompe-titioninaparticularindustry.
Wealsomeasuredthreemainliberalizationforcesatthefirmlevel:percentageofsalesex-ported,foreignjointventureexperienceandstockexchangelisting.Thepercentageofsalesexportedwasmeasuredbyaskingrespondentswhatper-
centageoftheirfirmÕsoutputwasexportedoutofthecountry.Foreignjointventureexperiencewasmeasuredbyaskingrespondentswhethertheirfirmwasinajointventurewithaforeignfirm.Adummyvariableof1wasallocatedtothoseSOEsinajointventureand0tothosethatwerenot.12Asforeignjointventureexperienceandsalesexportopportunitiesarepartlyafunctionoflocationandthesampleusedinthisstudywasgainedfromtwodifferentlocations(HubeiandGuangzhou)weincludedlocationasacontrolvariableinthisstudy.Adummyvariableof1wasallocatedtothoseSOEsinGuangdong,whichisacoastalprovinceandspecialeconomiczone,andazerowasallocatedtothoseSOEslocatedinHubei,whichisaninlandprovince.Whenlocationwasenteredintothemodelasanindependentvariableofthefourliberalizationforcesandpoliticalconstraints,thesignandsignificanceoftheparameterestimatesforallofthehypoth-esizedpathsremainedunchanged.
12168N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
StockmarketlistingcomprisedlistingontheShanghaiorShenzhenStockExchanges,andweusedadummyvariablewiththevalueof1iftheSOEwaslisted,and0ifnot.
Politicalconstraintsweremeasuredwithfiveob-servablemeasuresthatrelatedtohumanresourcedecision-makingauthority.Therewerefiveitemsinresponsetotwoquestions.Thefirstquestionaskedabouttheextenttowhichthegovernmentagency/ministrythatwasresponsiblefortheindus-try(item1)andtheCommunistPartyrepresenta-tive(item2)affectedthehumanresourcedecisions(hiring,firing,andpromotion)ofcostorprofitcentermanagersinthefirm.Thesecondquestionaskedabouttheextentofauthoritythatwasgiventotherepresentativefromthegovernmentminis-trytomakethefollowingdecisionsforthefirm:thehiring(item3),promotion(item4),andfiring(item5)ofcostorprofitcentermanagers.There-sponseswereanchoredonasevenpointLikertscalethatrangedfrom1(notatall)to7(averyhighextent).TheCronbach(1951)alphafortheitemswas0.92.
Size(numberofemployeesintheSOE)wasin-cludedasacontrolvariableintheanalysissinceitispositivelyassociatedwithbothagencyandpolit-icalcostsandhasbeenanimportantcriterionintheSOEreforms,asevidencedbygovernmentinterventioninlargerSOEs,whichcarryaheavierburdenintheformofsocial-welfarecosts(Goo-dall&Warner,1999;Lee,2001;Linetal.,1998).Thenaturallogarithmofthenumberofemployeeswasusedintheanalysis.
Organizationaldesigncomponents
Threeorganizationaldesigncomponentswereexaminedinthisstudy(delegation,objectiveper-formancemeasures,andincentives).WeadaptedtheKilling(1983)delegationmeasure,andaskedtherespondentsabouttheextenttowhichauthor-itywasdelegatedbytheseniormanagement(e.g.,thegeneralmanagerortheboardofdirectors)tocostorprofitcentermanagersindecision-makingareasthatwererelatedtothedevelopmentofnewproductsandprojects,thesourcingofinputs,thehiringandfiringofpersonnel,budgetsetting,andbudgetandnon-budgetspending.Thesixitemswereextractedfromnineitemsinthesurveyonthebasisoffacevalidity(budgetresponsibilityorientation)andconfirmatoryfactoranalysis(seethenextsection).A5itemresponsescalerangedfrom0(notatall)to5(averylargeextent).TheCronbach(1951)alphafortheitemswas0.74.Asacheckofdiscriminantvalidityitwasimportanttodistinguishbetweenpoliticalcon-straintsanddelegationvariablesbecauseitemsthatrelatetohiringandfiringappearinbothvari-ables.However,thecontextofeachisdifferentintermsof:(i)whohasthepower—forpoliticalcon-straintsitistheextenttowhichthePartymemberaffectshiring,promotion,andfiringdecisions,andfordelegationitistheextenttowhichauthorityisdelegatedtoprofit/costcentremanagers;and(ii)thescopeofeachvariable—delegationhasabroaderscopeinthatitseeksthelevelofdelega-tiononagreaterrangeoffactorsthanhumanresourcesmanagement.Thelownegativecorrela-tionbetweenthesetwomeasures(À0.219,seeTable3)alsoprovidessupportforthediscriminantvalidity.Aswillbeshownlater,allofthecon-structsloadedontoseparatefactors.
Wemeasuredtheextenttowhichobjectiveper-formancemeasureswereusedbyaskingabouttherelativeweight(between0%and100%)thatwasgiventoobjectiveorsubjectivecriteriainevaluat-ingtheperformanceofcostorprofitcenterman-agersforthepurposesof:(a)increasingtheirresponsibilities;(b)increasingtheirvariablebonussalarybasedonindividualperformance;(c)increasingtheirvariablebonussalarybasedoncost/profitcenterperformance;(d)increasingtheirvariablebonussalarybasedonoverallfirmperfor-mance;and(e)determiningnewcontractterms(ornon-renewal)attheendofthecurrentcontract.Tomakethiscleartotherespondents,wegavethemalistofobjectivecriteria(fourbudgetandaccount-ingitemstakenfromtheHopwood(1972)budgetemphasismeasure)andsubjectivecriteria(fourqualitativeitemstakenfromthesamework).TheresponsewassoughtonafivepointLikertscalethatrangedin25%incrementsfrom‘‘100%Obj’’(objectivemeasuresarethemostimportant)to‘‘100%Subj’’(subjectivemeasuresarethemostimportant).Transformationsofthescaleweremadetoindicatethelevelofobjectivemeasures,thusproducingarangefrom0%to100%objective
N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
Table3
Constructanderrormatrixes
Pearsoncorrelations
PoliticalIndustryExportconstraintsaliberalizationsales
forces
Industry
liberalizationforcesaExportsalesJointventureexperience
StockexchangelistingDelegationaObjective
performancemeasuresaIncentivesaSize
À0.097**À0.008À0.261**À0.138**À0.229**À0.203**À0.0300.201**
0.137**À0.0240.104**0.0610.0720.158**À0.067*
169
JointventureStockDelegationObjectiveIncentivesexperienceexchangeperformance
listingmeasures
0.0490.231**
0.254**À0.012
0.181**0.135**0.172**
0.119*0.0740.0370.122*
0.256**0.582**0.053
0.499**0.046
0.236**À0.0160.0880.083
À0.204*
*p<0.05;**p<0.01.
aVariablesrepresentfactorconstructscoresfromthesevenfactormodel;n=502.
measuresforeachofthefiveitems.TheCronbach(1951)alphaforthefiveitemswas0.80.13Theincentivesmeasurecomprisedtwocompo-nents:theShieldsandYoung(1993)incentivesinstrumentandtheaveragetotalmonthlyincomerangeforallcostorprofitcentermanagers.TheShieldsandYoung(1993)instrumentcomprisedthreeitems:theextenttowhichcompensationwasrelatedtomanagerialperformance;theextenttowhichmanagersinthetop25%ofperformersweregivenlargerrewardsthanthoseinthebottom25%;andtheextenttowhichfinancialrewardsin-creasedasactualperformanceexceededbudgetedperformance.Afiveitemresponsescalerangedfrom0(notatall)to5(verylargeextent).TheCronbach(1951)alphaforthethreeitemswas0.78.Fordeterminingtheaveragetotalmonthlyincomerangeforallcostorprofitcentermanag-
ers,weaskedtherespondentstoindicatethein-comelevelfor(a)thehighestperforming10%ofmanagersand(b)thelowestperforming10%ofmanagers.A6-itemresponsescalerangedfromYuan61000,1001–2500,2501–4000,4001–6000,and6001–10,000to>10,000.Thedifferenceinthesetworesponses(2setsof6-itemscales)wasdi-videdbythelowestperforming10%levelofmonthlyincometoobtainapercentagescore.Thedescriptivestatisticsofthevariablesarein-cludedinTable2.
Samplevalidityandreliability
Therespondentshadanaveragetermofemploymentof7years.ThissuggeststhattheyhadadequateSOEknowledgewithwhichtoan-swerthesurveyquestions.BecauseitispossiblethatmanagersÕknowledgeconcerningpoliticalconstraintsandpartsoforganizationaldesignmayvaryaccordingtothedivisionthattheyareinorthesizeoftheSOE,wemeasuredtheirdegreeofconfidenceintheiranswerstoitemsthatcom-prisefourvariables(politicalconstraints,delega-tion,objectiveperformancemeasuresandincentives)usinga5pointLikertscale(responsescale:1=verysmallextentto5=verylargeextent).Theaverageresponseacrossthefour
Asafurtherindicationofthereliabilityofthemeasure,wecitedtheactualrangeinresponseacrossthefiveitems.Withthetheoreticalrangebeing100%(i.e.,anindicationofsubjective(i.e.,0%)foroneitemandanindicationofobjective(i.e.,100%)foranotheritem)therewouldbeaconcernifasignificant(5%)portionofcaseshadarangethatwasmorethan50%.Outof502cases,in21(4.2%)therewasadifferenceof75%,andinone(0.2%)therewasadifferenceof100%.
13170N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
variablesrangedfrom3.233to3.750.WhilewefoundnosignificantdifferenceintheaveragelevelofrespondentconfidenceacrossvarioussamplesthatweresplitaccordingtothefivemaindivisionsandbetweenlargeandsmallSOEs,theaveragelevelofrespondentconfidencewasthelowestforthemeasureofincentives,thereforerelatedfind-ingsmustbeinterpretedwithsomecaution.
TheSOEsamplehadanaveragesizeof3020employees,exportedanaverage18%ofsales,andexhibitedanaverage15%salesgrowth.About16%oftheSOEswereapartnerinaforeign-Chi-nesejointventureand23%oftheSOEswerelistedonthestockexchange.Theaveragemonthlyman-agersalaryrangedfrom250to11,000Yuan,withameanof3395Yuan.Thisiscomparabletothelowermonthlysalaryof1500YuanthatGoodallandWarner(1999)reportfortheworkersin38SOEs.ComparisonswithindustrystatisticswereundertakentoprovidefurtherinsightintothevalidityofsomeSOEcharacteristics.Forexample,wecorrelatedthesalesgrowthoftheSOEwiththesalesgrowthcharacteristicsoftheSOEÕsindustryandobtainedalowbutsignificantPearsoncorrela-tionof0.12(p<0.01),whichisconsistentwiththeexpectationthatSOEsinhighergrowthindustrieswillexhibit,onaverage,higherlevelsofsalesgrowth.
Wealsomeasuredthepercentagelevelofbonus-basedsalary(bonuspay/basepay*100)byaskingrespondentstoindicatetheaveragelevelofbonususingthesame7itemscaleasbasepay(rangingfromlessthan500Yuantomorethan10,000Yuan).ThePearsoncorrelationbetweenthismeasureandthemeasureoftheaveragetotalmonthlyincomerangepercentagewas0.138(p<0.05).Substitutingthismeasureforthebonusmeasureinthemodelresultedinnodifferenceinthesignificanceoftheparameterestimates.Structuralequationmodel
Astructuralequationmodeling(SEM)ap-proachwasusedtoanalyzethesurveyandarchi-valdatausingtheSPSSxAMOS4.0statisticalpackage.Thefollowingequationsweresimulta-neouslytestedtoestimatetheparametersfortheinitial(unconstrainedpath)model.
DEL¼B0þB1OBJþB2INCþB3COMP
þB4EXPþB5JVþB6STOKþB7PCþB8SIZEþe
ð1Þ
OBJ¼B0þB1DELþB2INCþB3COMP
þb4EXPþB5JVþB6STOKþB7PCþB8SIZEþe
ð2ÞINC¼B0þB1DELþB2OBJþB3COMP
þb4EXPþB5JVþB6STOKþB7PCþB8SIZEþe
ð3ÞPC¼B0þB1COMPþB2EXPþB3JV
þB4STOKþB5SIZEþeð4ÞwhereDELdelegation
OBJobjectiveperformancemeasuresINCincentivecompensation
COMPindustrygrowthandcompetitionEXPexportsales
JVjointventureexperience(yes(1),no(0))STOKlistedonstockexchange(yes(1),no(0))PCpoliticalconstraints
SIZE
firmsize(logofnumberofemployees,usedasacontrolvariable)
TheSEMspecifiestherelationshipsbetweentheunobservedconstructs.Similartoasetofregres-sionequations,themodelisusedtodescribetheassociationsbetweenconstructs.However,incon-trasttoregressionmodels,thestructuralequationmodellinksunobserved(latent),hypotheticalcon-structsratherthanconcrete,empiricalindicators.Themodelinthisstudycomprisedfivelatentvari-ables(DEL,OBJ,INC,COMP,PC)andfourob-servedvariables(EXP,JV,STOK,SIZE)(seeFig.2).TheprincipaladvantageoftheSEMapproachisthatitgoesbeyondconventionallinearmodelsandaccountsformeasurementerror,allowsforsimultaneousestimatesofmeasurementandstruc-turalparameters,andhenceprovidesdiagnosticstatistics/informationforthemodelasawhole(Joreskog&Sorbom,1979).AnotheradvantageofSEMwastheabilitytomodelbi-directional
N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177171
Industry growth and Foreign competitionH2a--.17 (2.47)*DelegationExport salesH1.2a+.23 (3.31)**H3a--.30 (2.72)**.59 (4.03)**Political constraintsH3c-.30 (2.15)*IncentivesJoint venture experienceH2c--.36 (6.40)**.14 (2.05)*H3b--.29 (3.26)**Objective performance measures.42(3.73)**Stock exchange listing H2d--.14 (2.45)**Fig.2.Parameterestimatesofthemodifiedmodel.*p<0.05;**p<0.01.Theunconstrainedpathmodelincludesallofthepaths(dottedandsolid).Thesolidlinesformthemodifiedmodelofbestfit.Standardizedcoefficients(b)andplevelsaredisplayed(two-tailtest)forthesignificantpaths.Theparameterestimatesofthesizecontrolvariable(notshown)weresignificantforpoliticalconstraints(b=0.23**)andincentives(b=À0.38**).v2=395.894(261d.f.),AGFI=0.918,CFI=0.878andIFI=0.885.relationshipsbetweentwoormoreconstructs(seeByrne,2001,p.120),whichisanassumptionoftheorganizationaldesignframework(Milgrom&Roberts,1995).Assomeofourdataweremea-suredusingordinalscales(e.g.,delegationandobjectiveperformancemeasures)weusedtheGLSestimationmethod.AccordingtoGolob(2001,p.3),GLSestimationmethodsareusefulfordealingwithdiscretechoicevariablesandordi-nalattitudescales(suchastheLikertscale).14Confirmatoryfactoranalysis(CFA)
Inbuildingtheproposedsystemofrelation-ships,webegantheanalysisbyexaminingonlythemeasurementpropertiesoftheinitialmodel.WeconductedCFAtotestthegoodness-of-fitofthemodelthatcomprisedsize,liberalizationforcesattheindustry(growthandforeignmarketcompe-Thereisdebateintheliteratureabouttheappropriatenessofusingordinalmeasures(includingtheuseofdummyvariablestorepresentdifferentcategoriesinaparticularorder)(Golob,2001).ForgeneraldiscussionsofGLS,seeBrowne
´n(1984).(1984)andMuthe
14tition)andfirm(exportsales,jointventure,stock
exchange)level,politicalconstraints,delegation,objectiveperformancemeasures,andincentives(Bollen,1989).Theoverallmodelfitcouldbeas-sessedbytheChi-squaretest,andheuristicallybyanumberofgoodness-of-fitindices:theadjustedgoodness-of-fitindex(AGFI),therootmeansquareresidual(RMSR),theincrementalfitindex(IFI)andcomparativefitindex(CFI)(Anderson&Gerbing,1988;Bollen,1989).Thefitindicesindi-catetheextenttowhichtheassociationsbetweentheunobservedendogenousandexogenouslatentvariablesandtheirobservedindicatorsinthehypothesized(measurement)modelaresignifi-cantlydifferentfromarandomassociationsmodel.Valuesofgreaterthan0.80provideanacceptablelevelofincrementalfit(Carmines&Mclver,1981).Weperformedseveralcheckstogaugethepo-tentialthreatofmulticollinearityinthedata.First,wereviewedthecorrelationsamongthevariablesshowninTable3.Thecorrelationbetweentheindependent(dependent)variableswiththegreat-estmagnitudewas.261(.582),whichisbelowthecriterionof.80forthelevelofcorrelationthatindicatesaseriousmulticollinearityproblem
172N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
(Kennedy,1979).Asasecondcheckweranthefactoranalysiswithavarimaxrotationandsevenfactorsemergedthatcorrespondedtothevariablesinthemodel.This,alongwiththesignificantfitin-dexesfortheconfirmatoryfactoranalysismodelindicatedthatmulticollinearitywasnotaproblem.Table1showsthefactorloadingsforeachofthesevenconstructs.Althoughtheinitialfactoranalysisresultedinsevenfactors(thethreeliberal-izationforcesatthefirm-levelloadedontothesamefactor),weexpandedthemodeltoconsistofninefactors(fivelatentandfourdirectlyob-servedvariables).Thisenabledustotestthehypothesesbyexaminingtheseparatepathsper-tainingtoeachofthefirm-levelliberalizationforces.Theninefactor/variablemodelshowedgoodlevelsoffitagainstthebaselinemodelsandagainstthebenchmarkssetintheliterature(Bago-zzi&Yi,1988).15Thegoodness-of-fitindexeswerewithintolerableranges:(e.g.AGFI=0.917,RMSR=0.033,IFI=0.890,CFI=0.883).Allofthefactorloadingsofthemeasurementinstrumentexceededthe0.4levelthatiscommonlyconsideredmeaningfulinfactoranalysis(Ford,MacCallum,&Tait,1986).Thebi-variatecorrelationsofthefactors/variablescoresprovideaninitialindicationoftherelationshipsbetweenthemeasuredandla-tentvariables(seeTable3).
Results
Totestthehypotheses,wefirstassessedthemodelusingaseriesofnestedmodelsbeginningwiththeleastconstrainedmodel—onethatin-cludedallofthepathsthatwereshowninFig.2.16Todothis,someofthepathsinthemodelwereconstrained(i.e.,setequalto0),whichpre-15WemadeseveraladjustmentstotheparametersinfittingtheninefactorCFAmodel.Wefixedthecovarianceinerrortermsforseveralitemsthathadsimilarfacevalidityandthesameresponsescale.Wefixedtheerrortermforallitemsforpoliticalconstraintsanddelegation.Weappliedthesameconstrainttotwoobjectiveperformancemeasureitems(OBJ2andOBJ3)andthreeincentivesitems(REW1,REW2andREW3).16Tocontrolforsize,thepathsbetweensizeandpoliticalconstraintsandeachoftheorganizationdesignvariableswereincludedinallofthemodels.
ventedthemfromsubsequentlybeingestimated.Thesequenceofnestedmodelswasdeterminedbyeliminatingtheleastsignificantparameter(set-tingthepathequalto0).FollowingtheprocedurethatAndersonandGerbing(1988)suggested,wecomputedtheChi-squaredifferencesbetweeneachnestedmodelandtestedthemforsignificancebytakingintoaccountthedifferenceinthedegreesoffreedom.Asarule,ifchangeintheChi-squareisnotsignificant,themodelwiththeconstrainedpathisabetterfit(Anderson&Gerbing,1988).AsignificantchangeintheChi-squareindicatesthattheconstrainedpathshouldnotberemoved.Wecontinuedthisprocessuntilnofurtherimprovementscouldbemadeandthemodelwasthemostparsimonious.Thisanalysisproducedthefollowingmodifiedhypothesizedmodel(shownwiththesolidlinesinFig.2).Thegoodness-of-fitindexes(e.g.AGFI=0.918,RMSR=0.032,IFI=0.885,CFI=0.878)indicatedthatthemod-ifiedmodelfittedthedataverywell.
Themain-effecthypotheses(H1)proposedapo-sitiveanddirectassociationbetweenliberalizationforcesandeachoftheorganizationaldesigncom-ponents.Onlyone(exportsalesanddelegation)outof12possibleassociationswassignificantandpositive(H1.2a,b=0.23,p=0.001).Theremaininghypotheses(H2andH3)predictedthatthemaininfluenceofliberalizationforcesonorga-nizationaldesignwouldbeindirectviapoliticalconstraints.Fortheseindirectrelationships,thesignsandsignificancelevelsoftheparameteresti-matesprovidedsupportforfiveoutofthesixsub-hypotheses.Threeofthefourcausalpathsbe-tweenliberalizationforcesandpoliticalconstraintswerenegativeandsignificant.Thesewereindustrygrowthandcompetition(H2a,b=À0.17,p=0.013),jointventureexperience(H2c,b=À0.36,p=0.000)andstockexchangelisting(H2d,b=À0.14,p=0.014).Finally,hypothesesthreepredictedthatpoliticalconstraintswouldbenegativelyrelatedtoeachoftheorganizationaldesigncomponents.InresultsnotpresentedinFig.2,thepathbetweensizeandpoliticalconstraintswaspositiveandsignificant(b=0.23,p=0.000),whilethepathbetweensizeandincentiveswasnegativeandsignificant(b=À0.38,p=0.001).Andwhensizewascontrolled,thereremainedsig-
N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177173
nificanteffectsofpoliticalconstraintsonorganiza-tiondesigncomponents.Whilethenegativepathsthatlinkedpoliticalconstraintsanddelegation(H3a,b=À0.30,p=0.007)andobjectiveperfor-mancemeasures(H3b,b=À0.29,p=0.001)wereconsistentwithexpectations,thepositivepathbetweenpoliticalconstraintsandincentives(H3c,b=0.30,p=0.032)wasoppositetoexpecta-tions.17Theimportanceofpoliticalconstraintsasamediatingvariableisfurtherillustratedbyexamin-ingthebi-variateassociationsbetweenliberaliza-tionforcesandorganizationaldesigncomponents(seeTable3),inwhichthereisasig-nificantdirectrelationinsixoutoftwelvecases.Infourofthesesignificantrelations(excludingex-portsales)mostoftheobservedcorrelationisex-plainedduetotheindirecteffectviapoliticalconstraints.AspredictedinH2,politicalcon-straintsformanimportantmediatingfactorintheserelationships.Forthesixnon-significantbi-variateassociations,ourfindingsindicatethattheincreaseduseofdelegationandobjectiveper-formancemeasuresarisessolelyduetothelowerpoliticalconstraintsinresponsetoliberalizationforces(industry,jointventureexperience,andstockexchangelisting),aftercontrollingforsize.Thestrengthofthepoliticalconstraints-organiza-tionaldesignlinksrelativetotheliberalizationforceslinksfordelegationandobjectiveperfor-mancemeasuresisconsistentwithourhypothesis
17WhiletheSEMapproachwaschosentoanalyzethedata,wealsotestedthesamerelationshipswithaseriesofregressionmodels,oneforpoliticalconstraintsandforeachoftheorganizationaldesigncomponents.ThesignsandsignificanceoftheexpectedassociationswereconsistentwiththeSEMmodelinmostofthecases.ConsistentwiththeSEM,theregressionmodelforpoliticalconstraintswassignificant(AdjR-square=0.19)withtheestimatedcoefficientforsize(p<0.01)andthreeoutofthefourliberalizationforces(JV,STOKandCOMP)beingsignificant(p<0.05).Similarly,intheregressionsforbothDECandOBJ,theestimatedcoefficientforPCwasnegativeandsignificant(p<0.05).ForDEC,SIZEandEXPwerealsopositiveandsignificant(p<0.05),whileforREW,thecoefficientforOBJwaspositiveandsignificant.ContrarytotheSEM,theestimatedcoefficientsforJVandREWintheregressionmodelforOBJweresignificant.Finally,intheregressionofREW,thecoefficientforEXP(butnotDEC)waspositiveandsignificant(p<0.05).
thatpoliticalconstraintsandnotliberalizationforcesaredominantinorganizationaldesigninChineseSOEs.
Infocusingontheendogenousinfluencesbe-tweenthecomponents,thepartialresults—threeofthesixpaths(OBJtoDEL,OBJtoINC,andDELtoINC)weresignificantly(p<0.05)andpositivelyrelated—indicatethatwhilethechoiceofdelegationisafunctionofobjectiveperfor-mancemeasures,thechoiceofincentivesisafunc-tionofbothdelegationandobjectiveperformancemeasures.Thisevidencesuggeststheexistenceofsomeheterogeneityamongtheorganizationalde-signcomponents.Thatis,noteachofthesecom-ponentsisassociatedwithpoliticalconstraintsandliberalizationforcesinthesameorequalman-ner.Indeed,theabsenceofasignificantrelation-shippertainingtotheinfluenceofincentivesonboththelevelofdelegationorobjectiveperfor-mancemeasuresintheindirectmodelmightreflectthetransitionaleconomycontext,wherethelevelofriskthatisbornebytheagentmightnotbeaprimaryorganizationaldesigncriterion.18Overall,thestrengthofthepoliticalconstraints-organizationaldesignlinksrelativetotheliberal-izationforces-organizationaldesignlinksisconsis-tentwithourhypothesisthatitispoliticalconstraintsandnotefficiencythatisthedominantimperativedrivingorganizationaldesignintheChinareformsetting.
Conclusion
Themodelthatwedevelopinthispaperpro-videsageneraltheoreticalframeworktoexplainthedeterminationandevolutionofChineseSOEorganizationaldesign.Themodelrelatestheuseofthreeorganizationaldesigncomponentstofive
18InatestoftheclusteringeffectofthethreeorganizationaldesigncomponentswecomparedthefitofthefinalmodelinFig.2withthefitofamodelinwhichthejointpathsbetweenthethreecomponentswereallowedtobefreelyestimated.ThenewmodelhadabetterfitwithaChiSquareof386.651,whichwasadifferenceofninefortheextrathreedegreesoffreedomgiven.Whilethisindicatesapossibleclusteringeffect,ourdataislimitedinverifyingtheassumptionthatthethreecomponentsarejointlydetermined.
174N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
determinants:liberalizationforces(industry,ex-portsales,jointventureexperience,stockexchangelisting)andpoliticalconstraintsoverlabordeci-sion-makingintheSOE.Thismodelishelpfulinunderstandingvariationsintheorganizationalde-signamongChineseSOEs.Variousmarketliberal-izationforceshaveprovedtobeadeterminantfactorinthestructuringofSOEs.LiberalizationforcesstimulateSOEstosearchformoreefficientmanagementcontrolforms,whichincludethedel-egationofdecisionauthoritytodivision-levelmanagers,andthemoreextensiveuseofobjectiveperformancemeasuressuchasbudgetsand(indi-rectly)theprovisionofincentives.Incontrast,politicalconstraintsslowdownthetransitionofSOEstowardamoreefficiententerprise.AsChen(2000,p.47)pointsout,‘‘thegovernmenthasstrongincentivestodeviatefromtheprofitmaxi-mizationobjectivetopursueitsowngoals,suchasemploymentprovision,materialbalanceininput-output,tradepromotion,politicalcon-straintsandstabilization,etc.,atthecostoffirmefficiency.’’
Threekeyfindingsandcontributionshaveemerged.First,wefoundstrongersupportfortheindirectpathassociationsinwhichpoliticalconstraintsmediatetherelationshipbetweenliber-alizationforcesandtheuseofthreeorganizationaldesigncomponents.Withinthismodelourfindingthatpoliticalconstraintsareadirectnegativedeterminantofdelegationandobjectiveperfor-mancemeasuressupportsourargumentthatsuchcomponentshavethepotentialtodilutepoliticalconstraints.Thedirectpositiveinfluenceofpoliti-calconstraintsonincentivesmightbebecauseincentiveshavethepotentialtosupportthestatusquoifthebasisforincentivedeterminationiscon-sistentwiththeobjectivesofthepoliticalconstraint.
Second,theresultsextendthefindingsofFirth(1996)andOÕConnoretal.(2004)ontheinfluenceofliberalizationforcesontheSOEadoptionofWesternmanagementcontrols.Whilebothprevi-ousstudiesfoundlinearrelationshipsbetweenaspectsofmarketliberalization(marketcompeti-tionandjointventureexperience,Firth,1996;stockexchangelistingandjointventureexperi-ence,OÕConnoretal.,2004)andtheadoptionofmanagementaccountingmechanisms,thisstudyfoundthatthelevelofpoliticalconstraintsmedi-atestheinfluenceofthesethreefactors.Thenega-tivemediatinginfluenceofpoliticalconstraintsappearstobeconsistentwithourtheorythatsuchinterferenceimposesadditionalcostsonseniormanagementtodelegatemoreandtoimplementmoreobjectiveperformancemeasurement.Suchinterferencealsoimposescostsondivisionalman-agersduetothelimitedtransparencyandscopeforactionrequiredtomeetcertainperformancetargets.
Third,theresultscontributetotheChinaman-agementliterature(Goodall&Warner,1999;Groves,Hong,McMillan,&Naughton,1994;Li,2000;Shirley&Xu,1998;Xuetal.,2002).Inpar-ticular,ourresultsareconsistentwiththefindingsofShirleyandXu(1998)andXuetal.(2002),whosuggestthatthegovernmentdelegationofhumanresourcedecisionsisimportanttothecontinuedpaceofChinesestate-ownedenterprisereform.ForpolicymakersandotherswithaninterestinChina,andperhapsothercommandeconomies,thesefindingssuggestthatindustrygrowth,for-eigncompetition,jointventureexperienceandstockexchangelistingcanbepowerfulforcesintheadoptionofWesternorganizationaldesigncomponents.However,theyalsosuggestthatthechangeprocesscanbehamperedbyinstitutionalfactorssuchasgovernmentinvolvementinman-agement.Thisfindingsignificantlyaddstoourunderstandingofthetransitionaleconomycon-text,wherebythestateretainssignificantinfluenceinenterprisesthataredeemedtohavebeenpriv-atized.TheprocessoftransitionofSOEscontrastswiththeprivatizationfirststrategyfollowedinothertransitionaleconomiessuchasEasternEur-opeandtheformerrepublicsoftheSovietUnion.AccordingtoMcMillanandNaughton(1992),oneoftheuniquefeaturesofChinaÕsreformstrategyliesinitsslowdevelopmentofinstitutions(includ-ingmarkets)thatleadtogreatercompetitivepressure.
WhilethecurrentstudyhascontributedinsightsintothemoveofChineseSOEstowardtheuseofWesternorganizationaldesigncomponents,sev-erallimitationsareacknowledged.First,thestudyofthedesignofcontrolsystemsasadependent
N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177175
variableisjustifiedonthebasisthattheeconomyisinequilibriumandallformsareperformingoptimally.IntheChinareformcontextwherefirmsareinaconstantstateofflux,thisassump-tionislessrealistic.
Second,thefindingsaremainlybasedonman-agersÕperceptionsasreflectedintheirresponsestoasurvey,thusposingcommonmethodbias.Thenatureofthisbiasalsoprecludedusfromeffectivelyexaminingtheinfluencesofotherpoten-tialendogenousvariablessuchasstrategyandtaskuncertainty(Fisher&Govindarajan,1992);andpersonalfactors(e.g.,skillsandaspirations)orevenculturalfactors(e.g.,traditionalbeliefsaboutmanagement).Thereisaneedtotriangulatewithotherdatacollectiontechniques,suchasexamin-ingtheenterprisesÕprocedureandpolicymanualsandotherinternaldocuments.Third,theuseofaconveniencesamplejeopardizestheextenttowhichthesampleisrandom,andtheresultinginferencesthatcanbemadeaboutthegeneraliza-tionoftheresults.
Finally,althoughourstructuralequationesti-mateshaveconfirmedthevalidityofourmodelinwhichtheorganizationaldesigncomponentsaresimultaneouslyincludedasthedependentvari-ables,ourdata(basedoncross-sectionapproach)islimitedinverifyingthecausalorderwithrespecttothesequentialpathlinkingpoliticalorindustrialforcesandeachorganizationaldesigncomponent.Futureresearchmaymorethoroughlyverifythissimultaneityorcausalorderbycollectinganduti-lizingtimeseriesdatathatreflectslongitudinalpatternoforganizationaldesigncomponentsaswellaspoliticalandindustrialchanges.Suchrefinementscanshedlightontherelativeimpor-tanceofdifferentorganizationaldesigncompo-nentsbywhichtheChinesegovernmentimposespoliticalconstraints,andhowthismaydifferacrossenterpriseswithdifferentenvironmentsandcharacteristics.
Acknowledgements
EarlierversionsofthispaperwerepresentedattheUNSWManagementaccountingsymposium,Sydney,2003,theAFAANZconference,Brisbane,
2003,theAAAAnnualMeeting,Atlanta,2001,theAcademyofInternationalBusiness,Sydney,2001,andinseminarsattheUniversityofMel-bourneandMonashUniversity,July2002.Theauthorsareindebtedtotheparticipants,CheeChow,SueHaka,JoanLuft,GeorgeMilkovich,MichaelMorris,GordanRichardson,andMichaelShieldsfortheirsuggestionsandassistance.Theworkdescribedinthispaperwaspartiallysup-portedbyStrategicResearchGrant#7001016fromtheCityUniversityofHongKong.Thepaperhasbenefitedsignificantlyfromthecon-structivecommentsandadviceprovidedbytherefereesandtheeditor.
References
Anderson,J.C.,&Gerbing,D.W.(1988).Structuralequationmodellinginpractice:Areviewandrecommendedtwo-stepapproach.PsychologicalBulletin,103(May),411–423.
Bagozzi,R.,&Yi,Y.(1988).Ontheevaluationofstructuralequationmodels.JournaloftheAcademyofMarketingScience,16,74–94.
Bailey,J.,Chen,C.,&Dou,S.(1997).Conceptionsofselfandperformance-relatedfeedbackintheUS,Japan,andChina.JournalofInternationalBusinessStudies,28,605–625.
Baiman,S.,Larcker,D.F.,&Rajan,M.V.(1995).Organi-zationaldesignforbusinessunits.JournalofAccountingResearch(Autumn),205–229.
Baker,G.,Gibbons,R.,&Murphy,K.J.(1994).Subjectiveperformancemeasuresonoptimalincentivecontracts.QuarterlyJournalofEconomics(November),1125–1156.Baker,G.P.,Jensen,M.C.,&Murphy,K.J.(1988).Compensationandincentivespracticevs.theory.JournalofFinance,3,593–616.
Bollen,K.(1989).Structuralequationswithlatentvariables.NewYork:JohnWiley&Sons.
Branine,M.(1996).ObservationsontrainingandmanagementdevelopmentinthePeopleÕsRepublicofChina.PersonnelReview,25(1),25–39.
Brickley,J.A.,Smith,C.W.,&Zimmerman,J.L.(1995).Theeconomicsoforganizationalarchitecture.JournalofAppliedCorporateFinance,8(2),19–31.
Brickley,J.A.,Smith,C.W.,&Zimmerman,J.L.(2001).Managerialeconomicsandorganizationalarchitecture.USA:McGraw-HillIrwin.
Browne,M.W.(1984).Asymptoticdistributionfreemethodsinanalysisofcovariancestructures.BritishJournalofMath-ematicalandStatisticalPsychology,37,62–83.
Bushman,R.,Indjejikian,R.,&Penno,M.(2000).Privatepredecisioninformation,performancemeasurecongruity,andthevalueofdelegation.ContemporaryAccountingResearch,17(4),561–587.
176N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
Byrd,W.,&Tidrick,G.(1991).Themarketmechanismand
economicreformsinChina.Armonk:M.E.Sharpe.
Byrne,B.M.(2001).StructuralequationmodelingwithAMOS:
basicconcepts,applications,andprogramming.Mahwah,NewJersey:LawrenceErlbaumAssociatesInc.
Carmines,E.,&Mclver,J.(1981).Analysingmodelswith
unobservedvariables:analysisofcovariancestructures.InG.Bogrnstedt&E.Borgatta(Eds.),Socialmeasurement:currentissues.Sage:BeverlyHills.
Chen,C.C.(1995).Newtrendsinallocationpreferences:A
Sino-UScomparison.AcademyofManagementJournal,38,408–428.
Chen,H.(2000).TheinstitutionaltransitionofChina’stownship
andvillageenterprises.Aldershot:Ashgate.
Cheng,S.(2001).Studiesoneconomicreformsanddevelopment
inChina.NewYork:Oxford.
Child,J.(1994).ManagementinChinaduringtheageofreform.
Cambridge,England:CambridgeUniversityPress.
ChinaMarketsYearbook.,(2000).Shanghai:AllChinaMar-ketingResearchCo.,Ltd.
ChinaSecuritiesRegulatoryCommission.(2001).Introduction
toChinaSecuritiesMarket.Retrieved7November,2001,fromhttp://www.csrc.gov.cn/CSRCSite/eng/esmintr.htm.Christie,A.A,Joye,M.P.,&Watts,R.L.(2003).Decentral-izationofthefirm:theoryandevidence.JournalofCorporateFinance,9,3–26.
Cronbach,L.J.(1951).Coefficientalphaandinternalstructure
oftests.Psychometrika(September),297–334.
Delmastro,M.(2002).Thedeterminantsofthemanagement
hierarchy:evidencefromItalianplants.InternationalJour-nalofIndustrialOrganization,20(1),119–137.
Eisenhardt,K.M.(1989).Agencytheory:anassessmentand
review.AcademyofManagementReview,14(1),57–74.Firth,M.(1996).Thediffusionofmanagerialaccounting
proceduresinthePeopleÕsRepublicofChinaandtheinfluenceofforeignpartneredjointventures.Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety,21(7/8),629–654.
Fisher,J.,&Govindarajan,V.(1992).ProfitCenterManager
Compensation:Anexaminationofmarket,politicalandhumancapitalfactors.StrategicManagementJournal,13,205–217.
Ford,J.K.,MacCallum,R.C.,&Tait,M.(1986).The
applicationofexploratoryfactoranalysisinappliedpsy-chology:acriticalreviewandanalysis.PersonnelPsychol-ogy,39,291–314.
Gerhart,B.,&Milkovich,G.T.(1990).Organizational
differencesinmanagerialcompensationandfinancialper-formance.AcademyofManagementJournal,33(4),663–691.Gibbs,M.,Merchant,K.A.,VanderStede,W.A.,&Vargus,
M.E.(2004).Determinantsandeffectsofsubjectivityinincentives.Workingpaper,UniversityofChicago,Univer-sityofSouthernCaliforniaandUniversityofTexasatDallas.
Golob,T.F.(2001).TravelBehavior.Com:Activityapproaches
tomodelingtheeffectsofinformationtechnologyonpersonaltravelbehavior.InD.A.Hensher(Ed.),TravelBehaviourResearch:TheLeadingEdge.Oxford:Pergamon.
Goodall,K.,&Warner,M.(1999).Enterprisereform,labor-managementrelations,andhumanresourcemanagementinmultinationalcontext.EmpiricalevidencefromSino-foreignjointventures.InternationalStudiesofManagementandOrganization,29(3),21–36.
Groves,T.,Hong,Y.,McMillan,J.,&Naughton,B.(1994).
AutonomyandincentivesinChinesestateenterprises.QuarterlyJournalofEconomics,109,181–209.
Hassard,J.,Sheehan,J.,&Morris,J.(1999).Enterprisereform
inpost-DengChina.InternationalStudiesofManagement&Organization,29(3),54–83.
Haveman,H.A.(1992).Betweenarockandahardplace:
organizationalchangeandperformanceunderconditionsoffundamentalenvironmentaltransformation.AdministrativeScienceQuarterly,37(1),48–75.
Hopwood,A.G.(1972).Anempiricalstudyoftheroleof
accountingdatainperformanceevaluation.JournalofAccountingResearch(Suppl.),156–182.
Howell,R.,&Sakurai,M.(1992).Managementaccounting(and
other)LessonsfromtheJapanese.Boston,MA:HarvardBusinessSchoolPress.
Huang,Y.,&Duncan,R.(1997).HowsuccessfulwereChinaÕs
statesectorreforms?JournalofComparativeEconomics,24(1),65–78.
Ittner,C.D.,Larcker,D.F,&Meyer,M.W.(2003).
Subjectivityandtheweightingofperformancemeasure:Evidencefromabalancedscorecard.AccountingReview,78(3),725–758.
Jefferson,G.H.,&Rawski,T.G.(1994).Enterprisereformin
Chineseindustry.JournalofEconomicPerspectives,8,47–70.
Jefferson,G.H.,Rawski,T.G.,&Zheng,Y.(1996).Chinese
industrialproductivity:trends,measurementissuesandrecentdevelopments.JournalofComparativeEconomics,23,146–180.
Jensen,M.C.(1998).Foundationsoforganizationalstrategy.
Cambridge,Massachusetts:HarvardUniversityPress.
Jensen,M.C.,&Meckling,W.H.(1992).Specificandgeneral
knowledge,andorganizationstructure.InLarsWerin&HansWijkander(Eds.),Contracteconomics.Oxford:BasilBlackwell.
Jensen,M.C.,&Meckling,W.H.(1995).Specificandgeneral
knowledge,andorganizationalstructure.JournalofAppliedCorporateFinance,8(2),4–18.
Joreskog,D.G.,&Sorbom,D.(1979).Advancesinfactoranal-ysisandstructuralequationmodels.Cambridge,MA:ABT.Keating,A.S.(1997).Determinantsofdivisionalperformance
evaluationpractices.JournalofAccountingandEconomics,24(3),243–274.
Kennedy,P.(1979).Aguidetoeconometrics.Cambridge,MA:
MITPress.
Killing,J.P.(1983).Strategiesforjointventuresuccess.New
York:Praeger.
Lambert,R.A.,&Larcker,D.F.(1987).Ananalysisoftheuse
ofaccountingandmarketmeasuresofperformanceinexecutivecompensationcontracts.JournalofAccountingResearch,25,S85–S125.
N.G.O’Connoretal./Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety31(2006)157–177
177
Lee,C.W.(2001).Financialrestructuringofstateowned
enterprisesinChina:thecaseofShanghaiSunvePharma-ceuticalCorporation.Accounting,OrganizationsandSoci-ety,26,673–689.
Li,D.D.(2000).Insidercontrolvsgovernmentcontrol:astudy
ofChinaÕsstateenterprisesreform.WorkingPaper,HongKong:HongKongUniversityofScienceandTechnology.Li,W.(1997).Theimpactofeconomicreformonthe
performanceofChinesestateenterprises:1980–1989.Jour-nalofPoliticalEconomy,105,1080–1106.
Lin,J.Y.(2000).WTOaccessionandChinaÕsAgriculture.
ChinaEconomicReview,11(4),405–408.
Lin,J.Y.,Cai,F.,&Li,Z.(1998).Competition,policy
burdens,andstate-ownedenterprisereform.AmericanEconomicReview,88(2),422–427.
Luft,J.,&Shields,M.D.(2003).Mappingmanagement
accounting:graphicsandGuidelinesfortheory-consistentempiricalresearch.Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety,28,169–249.
McMillan,J.,&Naughton,B.(1992).Howtoreformaplanned
economy:lessonsfromChina.OxfordReviewofEconomicPolicy,8(1),130–143.
Megginson,W.L.,&Netter,J.M.(2001).Fromstateto
market:asurveyofempiricalstudiesonprivatization.JournalofEconomicLiterature(June),1–89.
Mendelson,H.(2000).Organizationalarchitectureandsuccess
intheinformationtechnologyindustry.ManagementSci-ence,46,513–529.
Merchant,K.A.(1989).Rewardingresults:motivatingprofit
centermanagers.Boston:HarvardBusinessSchoolPress.Milgrom,P.,&Roberts,J.(1992).Economics,organization,and
management.EnglewoodCliffs:Prentice-Hall.
Milgrom,P.,&Roberts,J.(1995).Complementaritiesandfit:
strategy,structure,andorganizationalchangeinmanufac-turing.JournalofAccountingandEconomics,19(2–3),179–209.
Moers,F.(2005).Discretionandbiasinperformanceevalua-tion:theimpactofdiversityandsubjectivity.Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety,30(1),1–98.
Muthe
´n,B.(1984).Ageneralstructuralequationmodelwithdichotomous,orderedcategoricalandcontinuouslatentvariableindicators.Psychometrika,49,115–132.
Nagar,V.(2002).Delegationandincentivecompensation.
AccountingReview,77(2),379–395.
OÕConnor,N.G.,Chow,C.W.,&Wu,A.(2004).Theadoption
of‘‘Western’’managementaccounting/controlsinChinaÕsstate-ownedenterprisesduringeconomictransition.Accounting,OrganizationsandSociety,29(3–4),349–375.Pannier,D.(1996).Corporategovernanceofpublicenterprises
intransitionaleconomies.WorldBankTechnicalPaper323.Peng,M.W.,&Heath,P.S.(1996).Thegrowthofthefirmin
plannedeconomiesintransition:Institutions,organizations,
andstrategicchoice.AcademyofManagementReview,21,492–528.
Perkins,D.(1994).CompletingChinaÕsmovetothemarket.JournalofEconomicPerspective,8(2),23–46.
Prendergast,C.(1999).Theprovisionofincentivesinfirms.JournalofEconomicLiterature(March),7–63.
Priem,R.L.,&Rosenstein,J.(2000).Isorganizationtheoryobvioustopractitioners?Atestofoneestablishedtheory.OrganizationScience,11(5),509–524.
Qian,Y.(1996).EnterprisereforminChina:Agencyproblemsandpoliticalcontrol.EconomiesofTransition,4(2),427–447.
Qian,Y.(2001).HowreformworkedinChina.WorkingPaper.DepartmentofEconomics,UniversityofCalifornia,Berke-ley,CA.
Shields,M.,&Young,S.M.(1993).Antecedentsandconse-quencesofparticipativebudgeting:evidenceontheeffectsofasymmetricalinformation.JournalofManagementAccount-ingResearch,5,265–280.
Shirley,M.,&Xu,L.C.(2001).Empiricaleffectsofperfor-mancecontracts:evidencefromChina.JournalofLaw,Economics,&Organization,17(1),168–200.
Shirley,M.,&Xu,L.C.(1998).Information,incentivesandcommitment:anempiricalanalysisofcontractsbetweengovernmentandstateenterprises.JournalofLaw,Econom-ics,andOrganization,14(2),358–378.
Shleifer,A.,&Vishney,R.W.(1994).Politiciansandfirms.QuarterlyJournalofEconomics,109,995–1025.
Simons,R.(1995).Leversofcontrol:Howmanagersuseinnovativecontrolsystemtodrivestrategicrenewal.Boston:HarvardBusinessSchoolPress.
Tosi,H.L.,Katz,J.P.,&Gomez-Mejia,L.R.(1997).Disaggregatingtheagencycontract:theeffectsofmonitor-ing,incentivealignment,andterminofficeonagentdecisionmaking.AcademyofManagementJournal,40,584–602.Wang,J.(2003).Governanceroleofdifferenttypesofstateshareholders:evidencefromChinaÕslistedcompanies.WorkingPaperpresentedattheAsia-PacificJournalofAccounting&EconomicsConference,Shanghai,China.Xu,L.C.(2000).Control,incentivesandcompetition.Eco-nomicsofTransition,8(1),151–172.
Xu,L.C.,Zhu,T.,&Lin,Y.M.,(2002).Politicalcontrol,agencyproblemsandownershipreform:evidencefromChina.WorkingPaper.Washington,D.C.WorldBank.Young,A.M.(2000).Theroleofindividualdifferencesinthereferentselectionprocess.JournalofBehavioralandAppliedManagement,1(1),83–91.
Zhongguo,G.B.(1997).China-culture:performancereviewsdiscussed.BeijingReview,1.
Zhuang,J.,&Xu,C.(1996).Profit-sharingandfinancialperformanceintheChinesestateenterprises:evidencefrompaneldata.EconomicsofPlanning,29,205–222.
因篇幅问题不能全部显示,请点此查看更多更全内容